<<<<Previous page | |
<<<Previous section | Next section>>> |
"If you want people to fight, throw them a bone; If you want them to cooperate, have them build a tower."
--Saint-Exupéry, Citadel
Today, local currencies are again mushrooming all over the world
in an impressive diversity and increasing sophistication. As
Hazel Henderson has pointed out, the key to the success of a
community currency, just as for any currency, is trust. In this case it
is trust in your neighbors, in the community as a whole, and in
the community's leaders.
My focus here is limited to emphasizing that once you have
decided to have a community currency, why not use the best
design available? It is important that community currencies
concentrate exclusively on the two key functions of money--standard of value and means of exchange--and therefore discourage
the use of this money as a store of value or a means
of speculation. The best way to ensure this, in particular for
the more sophisticated electronic forms of local currency now
coming online (for example, the Minneapolis Commonweal
experiment), is to build in a booster or another form of the
demurrage concept.
The majority of the present systems simply use a "zero interest"
concept. In contrast, the majority of local currencies implemented
in the 1930s explicitly built in the demurrage idea, typically
through the process of requiring periodic application of
stamps. Stamps are a primitive way of achieving the desired
objective; today, with smart cards or electronic accounting for
local exchange (LETS) systems, demurrage could be achieved
much more effectively and conveniently by simply programming
a small charge on outstanding balances.
This small step would have several substantial benefits:
Every participant in the local currency system will become a
motivated promoter. One of the features that many organizers of
LETS systems have noticed is that over time the originators tend
to remain the dominant force promoting the system to new users.
Some systems simply die when their original promoter is no
longer available for this. Paul Glover, the founder of the Ithaca
money system, mentioned that he spends a good deal of his time
convincing new participants to accept the money.(note 10) This is
typical, because the other members have no major incentive to actively
promote new participants: they can just keep the currency
until they have some use for it. In contrast, in Worgl or in
Swanenkirchen in 1930, each participant was personally
motivated to convince his butcher, baker, or cousin to accept the
money. One of the reasons that local currencies have multiplied
in number today but have not spread as widely as in the 1930s is
this structural difference in motivation for member participants.
More jobs will be created. Community currencies now tend
to create no more jobs in the community than normal currencies.
This was not the case in Worgl, for instance, where we noticed
that every shilling of Worgl money created fourteen times more
jobs than a normal national Shilling.
Community spirit will be fostered. In many cases, the motivation
for introducing community currencies today is often
less to create jobs than to foster community spirit. Community
currencies are indeed one of the most effective tools to
achieve this. The word community appeared first in written
English in 1283. It is etymologically derived from the Old
French and Late Latin, where it referred to a group of monks
who owned, operated, and lived from the fruits of their
monastery. In other words, it referred to the material organization
of a self-contained economic entity. Benedictus of Aniane (5th
Century) felt that such a process would automatically support
the sharing of the spiritual objectives of their members.
Consciously promoting more frequent interactions and interdependencies
with your neighbors has therefore long been
successful in generating this elusive quality of community
spirit. Building in the booster concept or another form of demurrage
would increase the density of these interactions and
therefore also spread its benefits.
Hoarding will become ill advised. Some community currencies
have experienced the hoarding phenomenon. Sometimes this
is even interpreted as a sign of success, because
such behavior reproduces more closely the use of "normal"
currency. But every time someone hoards the community currency,
he or she is depriving others of its benefits. In addition,
as was shown earlier in the discussion of conflict between
the store-of-value and medium-of-exchange functions,
there are even structural reasons why hoarding should be
avoided.
Ecologically sustainable practices will occur spontaneously
on a collective level. While other avenues can be used to promote
sustainable behaviors, including regulations and education,
why should we not use all the available tools? Reprogramming
the "invisible hand" to push for ecologically sustainable behavior
would be extremely helpful.
These benefits will become generalized only if and when
demurrage currency becomes the dominant currency. This circumstance
is less farfetched than it appears, for some community currencies
could play the role of prototype experiments in preparation for a new Bretton Woods agreement.
Next | Previous | Top |